Tuesday, 26 June 2018

Soil health, natural capital and post-Brexit soil policy


Ahead of Groundswell 2018, I thought I would share some thoughts on this year’s theme of soil health, and consider how this key idea looks from the perspective of farmers, researchers and policy makers.  It seems highly likely that payments to farmers will be overhauled in the next decade with Michael Gove currently keen to describe himself as “such an enthusiast for the idea of natural capital” (https://www.gov.uk/government/speeches/green-brexit-a-new-era-for-farming-fishing-and-the-environment).  With this is mind I think it is worth considering: where the idea of natural capital comes from and what it means; the relationship between soil natural capital and soil health; how farmers can influence soil natural capital/health and what a policy based on soil natural capital might look like.  The natural capital concept has been criticised where it is applied to all of nature.  Whilst I recognise these criticisms, I would argue that the natural capital perspective and soil management make a good fit.  That’s not to say that a policy based on a natural capital perspective would automatically be successful, there are many complications to be resolved and an evidence base which needs to be developed further.

The natural capital approach is based on four simple and connected ideas: 1) nature provides benefits (or costs) to humans; 2) we are not very good at valuing these benefits and costs, often undervaluing them or ignoring them completely; 3) undervaluing the benefits natural systems provide to humans results in these natural systems being degraded or destroyed; and 4) if the benefits of natural systems are better evaluated then natural systems will be better managed. 

The ecosystem services framework is a way of thinking the work which nature does and humans benefit from.  This could mean the production of food, improvements to our shared environment (e.g. reductions in water pollution or flooding) and simply providing a spiritually or emotionally fulfilling vista.  Historically, the benefits of nature’s work which could be harvested by one individual and sold to another (e.g. food production) have been relatively well valued, whilst the ways in which nature improves our shared environment have not.  The capacity of a natural system to provide benefits to humans will depend, in part, upon the state of that natural system.  In terms of soils, a compacted soil will be less capable of storing water and supporting crop growth.  This capacity of a soil (or other natural system) to provide benefits to humans can be termed natural capital.  For reference, within academia, natural capital is defined as “stocks of natural resources found on earth yielding a flow of valuable ecosystem goods or service into the future.” (Jónsson and Davídsdóttir, 2016).

This brings us to the CAP reform and Michael Gove’s fondness of the idea of natural capital.  It’s worth making clear that the language of natural capital, ecosystem services and payments for ecosystem services were developed with the aim of being policy and business friendly, and it appears to be working.  The central idea behind Gove’s thinking seems to be that the public money which will replace CAP funding should be used to generate benefits which the public benefit from.  This challenge produces two separate apparently similar options with significantly different implications.  The first is to pay farmers to improve the natural capital of their soil, that is the capacity to generate ecosystem services.  After all, a nation’s soil is an extremely valuable asset, so why not pay farmers to preserve and increase the value of this asset?  The second option is to pay farmers for the ecosystem services they generate. Because this option is so context dependent and responsive- where there is no storm then a soil won’t be able to reduce downstream flooding- it doesn’t appear to be viable.  Instead, a payment for effort (rather than payment for results) model seems more sensible.
This brings me to the issue of how paying farmers to improve their soil’s natural capital overlaps with paying farmers to improve their soil health.  As far as I am concerned, they are exactly the same thing.  They both mean the capability of a soil to indefinitely do work (e.g. support crops, mitigate flooding, not reduce water quality, store carbon…) which benefits people.  Indeed, it is the work which soils can do to regulate carbon storage and water quality which John Cherry discusses in his introduction to Groundswell 2018. 

I want to finish on five points: 1) context is everything when it comes to soil health, improving aggregate stability and protecting soil from raindrop impact to prevent water erosion is more valuable on a steeply sloping field next to a watercourse than on a heavier soil in Lincolnshire; 2) soil health is complex with many different dimensions, whilst it can be tempting to focus of a single aspect (like preventing erosion) it is important to look at the bigger picture (especially for researchers and policy makers); 3) The onus is on researchers to provide the evidence base to support any policies and 4) creating this evidence base won’t be cheap and will require collaboration with farmers, collaboration which will be most effective when farmers and researchers work together, respecting the knowledge and innovation of the other; and 5) getting policy right is another problem in its own right.

Thank you for taking the time to read this.  I would love for it to be the start of a conversation so please come and grab me at Cranfield’s spot at Groundswell 2018 or write a blog of your own in reply.  Lastly, if you are interested in an example of the payment for ecosystem services idea working well then check out how protecting woodland improved water quality, saving New York billions of $s https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/200901/pb13932a-pes-bestpractice-annexa-20130522.pdf) .  Also, a recent estimate put the value of money paid to individuals and organisations to manage natural systems to improve water quality at $24.7 billion (https://sustainabilitycommunity.nature.com/users/85108-james-salzman/posts/31181-global-market-for-ecosystem-services-surges-to-36-billion-in-annual-transactions ). 
P.P.S, for a counter argument to the idea of paying for ecosystem services, see https://theecologist.org/2018/apr/23/why-michael-gove-musnt-regard-our-planet-just-natural-capital


Friday, 27 October 2017

A conservationist's perspective on soil science

I studied ecology and conservation as an undergraduate before taking the opportunities available to me and beginning a PhD investigating the sustainability of agricultural practices, particularly tillage (the preparation of soil for the planting of a crop).  I’m not from a farming background and had not studied soil science extensively before my PhD so faced a steep learning curve (a reason for my lack of blogging).  However, my education as an undergraduate equipped me with ways of thinking which could be addressed to this new context.  I’m writing this blog for two reasons and two audiences:  I want to promote soil science to those interested in ecology and conservation who may not have an agricultural or soil science background and I want to share a way of thinking about soil management which I hope might ring true to the farmers acting as custodians of our soils.

To me, the essence of conservation science is identifying situations in which the ability of nature to provide benefits to humans is threatened or being degraded.  Often these situations exist because of a lack of awareness of either the benefits that healthy ecosystems deliver or the impact of a practice on the ability of an ecosystem to continue to deliver these benefits.  The hope is that by making the value of a healthy ecosystem clear individuals or companies are motivated to protected its health and reap the rewards themselves (e.g. water companies working to restore upland peat ecosystems to save on water processing costs) or government actions can be taken to protect ecosystems which provide benefits to many people (e.g. national parks protected so that the public can benefit from spending time in these spaces).  Where the benefits or changes to the ecosystem are less visible then degradation is more likely. 

To state the obvious, food is a basic human requirement and you can’t grow (the vast majority) of it without soil.  It’s also valuable for its role in regulating the quality of water and the flow of water through the environment.  And, crucially, not all soil is equal.  Just as a dense, wide mangrove forest provides better flood protection than a narrow, sparse forest the ability of a soil to support crop growth and regulate water quality will depend on its properties.  This is where soil science gets more complex.  The ability of a soil to deliver these benefits will be determined by a range of chemical, biological and physical properties of the soil, all of which are interlinked and many of which are hard to observe by eye.  Soil degradation may go largely unnoticed, obscured by the use of fertilisers to compensate for a reduction in the soil’s capacity to cycle nutrients or the use of tillage to restructure soil whilst any changes in yield can be easily attributed to a year’s weather.  In fact, it might not be until an extreme weather event that the costs of soil degradation become visible in the form of brown runoff carrying valuable topsoil (and the associated nutrients) from the field to watercourses where it contributes to sedimentation and nutrient pollution.

Soil health (the ability of a soil to provide the required benefits) is affected by farming operations and tillage is the one I am most interested in.  Tillage can involve flipping the soil over (i.e. ploughing), or chopping and mixing soil, breaking up the soil structure.  The full range of pros and cons of tillage and synergies between reducing tillage and other practices such as cover cropping and glyphosate use are a topic for another day.  For now, I want to present tillage to (non-soil) ecologists and conservationists as a wonderful example of a ‘disturbance event’.  By rearranging the soil structure and killing many organisms (e.g. earthworms and fungi), tillage is analogous to hurricane or forest fire and the same questions apply (i.e. how long do biological communities take to recover? and what is the relationship between the intensity of the disturbance event and the effect on the biological community?) .  Whilst studying forest fires and hurricanes leaves you largely at the whim of nature, tillage is a disturbance event which you can have under your own control.  It affects an incredibly biodiverse system which underpins the generation of vitally important services such as nutrient cycling, soil structuring and biodegradation of pollutants.

As an undergraduate I preferred ecology to pathology because I preferred studying organisms and systems which I could see with a naked eye.  To me, conservation science is about identifying the overlooked, and for most of my life, soil hid in plain sight.  I have to encourage any ecology and conservation undergraduates to take a good look at soil ecology. 


To farmers, this is not meant as an attack on tillage or a plea for minimum or zero tillage systems, that’s something which I will address in another blog. 

Monday, 19 June 2017

Blogging again

In the summer of 2014 I began a PhD in soil science and I am now drawing towards the end of it.  As I think is usual, the first two years of the PhD felt hectic, to say the least.  Now, as I begin my write up, I have time to reflect on my research and am bring the approach I developed as an undergraduate to bear on this new context.

And what a context.  Soil has been called “the poor [wo]man’s tropical rainforest” due the mind boggling diversity and complexity of its microbial, mesofaunal and macrofaunal communities and it has a complex 3d structure.  Unlike a tropical forest, if you want to investigate the effect of a disturbance event you don’t need to wait for a hurricane, climb trees and smoke out species or set up large scale deforestation plots, you can arrange tillage treatments with a farmer or simply take intact soil, pass it through a sieve and repack it.  If working with soil is like working with Arabidopsis or mice, it makes experiments in tropical forests look like working with redwoods or elephants.


So, some thoughts on the valuing our soils and what the valuing of this vitally important natural resource means for farming will follow, hopefully you will find them interesting.

Wednesday, 3 September 2014

Making Space to Fail


I’ve just finished a Master’s project investigating the movement of pathogens from the faeces of cattle to the sea where people swim.  The pattern of and processes involved are fairly poorly understood, especially the movement of pathogens from stream to sea.  It’s the first time I’ve been involved in studying such a complex and incompletely understood system and it’s been great.  With so much to learn and the need for both a better knowledge of the patterns of pathogen abundance and the need to better understand the processes responsible for I’ve found value in pursuing and range of questions and approaches.

A large part of my research work involved regular field work to collect data for a long term data set and the analysis of this data set.  I could be highly confident that this work would produce valuable insights.  With data collection and analysis planned out in advance I still had some spare time in which to speculate, producing and testing hypotheses.  I had room for many small failures.  With the large knowledge gaps, curiosity and the room to fail came a healthy attitude towards failure.  Being aware of my ignorance, and the ignorance of the larger scientific community meant that finding processes to be not significant genuinely felt like a valuable lesson learnt.  The cost of learning these lessons was low.  Materials were extremely cheap, the lab work for preliminary experiments took at most a few hours and I didn’t need to prove my hypotheses to be correct, on top of the long term dataset work any findings were a bonus.


Having benefitted from this set up I’m a big fan of differentiating one’s work into that which is extremely likely to produce valuable knowledge (even if only moderate amounts) and that which is more speculative.  Google do something similar with 20% time encouraging employees to spend 20% of their time working on curiosity driven projects not related to the rest of their work  (see Adapt by Tim Harford for an elaborated discussion of this idea or his talk on the subject).  Ideally research as a whole should be a space for failure but funders want results, significant results are more likely to be published and referenced than non-significant ones and unless we are extremely self-confident we struggle to do research without wanting to prove our ideas (and therefore ourselves) to be right.  One solution is to have so many ideas you can’t get attached to any of them, another is to view producing hypotheses like making bets, good bets often lose, to paraphrase Nicolas Nassim Taleb, a mistake is not something to be identified with hindsight but identified at the time with the information available.  In producing a hypothesis we place a bet using the information available.  The greater the rewards the more speculative our hypotheses can afford to be and the more speculative we are they more we have to expect to disprove our hypothesis.

Sunday, 17 November 2013

Erich Fromm and Conservation Science

To be successful conservation must alter the actions of individuals.  To alter the actions of individuals it is helpful to first understand human nature.  This is the realm of philosophy and psychoanalysis, of ideas resulting from slow and deep thinking not necessarily tested through experiments.  Instead of writing about what conservation can learn from other sciences, today I will write about what conservation can learn from the social sciences, particularly from Erich Fromm.

Eric Fromm (1900-1980) was a psychoanalyst (the Freudian school of psychology) and a social psychologist.  His ideas were not the results of experiments and consequent adjustments.  He worked up from the principles he believed to govern human behaviour, principles from philosophy, psychoanalysis and his own experiences and observations.  In ‘To have or to be?’, his 1976 book, Fromm wrote that most individuals “identify themselves by the following formula: I am=what I have and what I consume” and, consequently, in a conservation between two individuals of differing opinions “Each identifies with his own opinion.  What matters to each is to find better, i.e, more reasonable, arguments to defend his position.  Neither expects to change his own opinion, or that his opponent’s opinion will change.  Each is afraid of changing his own opinion, precisely because it is one of his possessions, and hence its loss would mean an impoverishment”.

I was first reminded of this passage when reading a paper advocating that scientists should not limit themselves to one theory (to prevent them from becoming too attached), instead they should suggest as many possible theories as possible and design experiments with the aim of disproving them.  It makes intuitive sense that individuals get attached to their ideas; Fromm offers a framework for understanding this.  He suggests that people derive their value, their self-worth from the ideas they create and then consume.  To lose an idea (to scientific progress) is just like losing another possession.

Fromm’s theory also has powerful ramifications for understanding the public’s stance on and engagement with issues of science such as global warming and GM technologies.  According to Fromm, an idea’s value is not a function of the idea’s use as a tool for making sense of the world (its usefulness); instead an idea’s value is determined by the cost of disowning that idea if a new, incompatible one is adopted.  More useful (i.e. correct) ideas do not necessarily replace less useful ideas, this means the initial ideas one creates regarding a subject are self-reinforcing and therefore very important.

Recently, the Cultural Cognition Project has produced quantitative evidence to support Fromm’s theory (I’m not sure if they were aware of Fromm’s work or not).  Their research showed citizens presented with expert sources regarding climate change were more likely to judge the expert source to be “knowledgeable and trustworthy” when the expert’s view agreed with their own.  Another study (by the same research group) reports that “Members of the public with the highest degrees of science literacy and technical reasoning capacity were not the most concerned about climate change” (authors’ italics).  The polarised opinions of two groups, separated on the basis of their political values, diverged as scientific literacy and technical reasoning increased, exactly as Fromm’s theory (“what matters to each is to find better, i.e, more reasonable , arguments to defend his position”) predicts.  

Andrew Balmford showed that children are better at identifying pokemon than real species (see here), might this be partly due to an ability to take ownership of pokemon (via card and computer games) which does not exist for real species (other than pets)?  How could this ownership be best replicated for real species?

Fromm suggests that keeping an open mind and avoiding dogmatism is difficult and requires active effort.  I suggest that it is the scientist’s role to purposefully keep an open and unbiased mind whilst they practice science, in their personal life, as with the rest of the public, they are free to respond to evidence however they like.

Friday, 8 November 2013

Conservation, a subject or a method?


A few months ago I sat down with the aim of describing exactly what conservation science is with the hope of producing a sort of framework.  I struggled.  I struggled because, trying to describe a science, I attempted to outline the conservation science method.  Pathology has a method and economics has a method; conservation science (if it can be called a science) does not have a method.  This is because conservation is a subject in the same way that, for example, asking how a healthcare system could be improved would be a subject.  To improve a healthcare system one would need not only look at biomedical research but also how to engineer the best buildings, how to attract and train the best staff, how to alter the public’s behaviour (in an acceptable manner) such that the demands on the system were reduced and how to best use the available staff, buildings and other resources.  In this blog I will explore the different strands of research which could and do contribute to the field of conservation highlighting that, in such a complex subject, explicitly defining the question one is answering and the framework they are using is vitally important.

I completed my undergraduate studies at Cambridge where, without really realising the significance at the time, I was introduced to three academics using and investigating different, complementary conservation methods. Head of conservation research for the RSPB, Rhys Green lectured me on a problem solving, investigative method used to isolate the factor causing the decline of vultures in Asia.  This was the similar approach to my idea of science, based on lab science.  William Sutherland introduced me to horizon scanning, a method to identify the upcoming challenges for conservation in conjunction with policy makers.  This type of research is obviously well complemented by the problem solving approach Rhys Green expounded.  William Sutherland also introduced me to citizen science, a framework for harnessing the information generated, often without being captured, by conservation practitioners.  This framework also has the potential to complements the Rhys Green framework, generating the data necessary to find solutions. 
Andrew Balmford, in my opinion a person who excels at providing the framework in which problems are best considered also lectured me.  Above all else, his lectures highlighted to me the need to identify the correct currency with which to measure the success of conservation efforts and the inevitable trade-offs entailed.  If you want to know how successful a zoo in then you must define success, is it visitor numbers or changes in individuals’ attitudes towards nature or the number of successful reintroductions or profits?  Are zoos trying to maximise the same measure of success as conservation scientists?  This approach largely influenced my blog on Quality Adjusted Life Years (QUALYs), the metric used by the NHS to quantify the value of different treatments.  It is also largely through the work of Andrew Balmford that I was introduced to the ecosystem services approach, an attempt to find a common currency which will allow conservation to engage with economics and politics, the forces which, ultimately, shape human behaviour and therefore the fate of nature (again, my blog on QUALYs examines this issue).

This last year, since graduating, I have discovered two new methods which, I believe, have much to offer to conservation.  The first is behavioural economics.  I have stated that economics and politics shape human behaviour but economics does not provide a perfect prediction of human behaviour.  Understanding why individuals act ‘non-rationally’ (not as an economic model would predict) is the realm of behavioural economics.  I believe that it will prove to be extremely valuable by aiding our understanding of the decision making of individuals, such as farmers, whose actions determine the fate of nature.  Once these decision making processes are understood, policy makers will be able to offer farmers, and other stewards of nature, the rewards they will respond to in exchange for actions which benefit nature (identified via traditional research and Sutherland’s citizen science).  Here is a link to a blog I wrote on what behavioural economics can offer conservation.  The second is no so much a method as a way of thinking (at least to me, perhaps I am not intelligent enough to convert this new awareness into a method).  It comes from the books of Nicholas Nassim Taleb, ‘Fooled by Randomness’ and ‘The Black Swan’.  These books provide a way of thinking about randomness in complex systems, and, ultimately conclude that it is better to be broadly right when making ecological predictions and designing conservation interventions than attempting to make precise predictions and being wrong.  If policy makers can be convinced that they are better served by uncertain predictions which include a measure of the uncertainty entailed, then the conservation would, I believe, benefit.  I have also written this blog on this subject.


Though I have characterised the three Cambridge professors as each pursuing different methods, in reality they co-operate and their work overlaps greatly.  In such an interdisciplinary field, collaboration within and between departments offers so much.  I think I will return to my blog and try to bring these strands and methods together into some sort of framework.  If you have any comments or advice then please do leave your thoughts below.  Many thanks.

Monday, 7 October 2013

Portraying the opinion of the scientific community in media debates

Consider the case of GM foods or Climate Change.  I want to know why the public assess risk differently from scientists and other experts.  It is a problem with many components of which I will only investigate one: how is the balance of ‘opinion’ within science, communicated to the public?  The norm for televised discussions or debates is to have on one side of the table the individual representing the consensus position and on the other side an individual representing the non consensus position.  I don’t believe that this format communicates to the public an accurate reflection of what scientists think.

Take for example the recent IPCC report which states with 95% confidence that humans are the ‘dominant cause’ of global warming.  At the most basic level, I believe, that having one scientist advocating the consensus position and one individual representing the 5% of uncertainty in a debate leaves the public with the impression that something akin to equal weight should be given to each side of the debate.   I would like to see the physical set up of the discussion reflect the actual balance of confidence (which in turn reflects the evidence).  This could be achieved by giving 95% of the airtime to the consensus position but I would not advocate this approach as it would limits the opportunity of the ‘non-consensus’ position to challenge the consensus position.  I am all in favour of the consensus position being scientifically challenged, it is through challenging and improving many generations of old scientific ideas and models that we arrived at the scientific understanding we have today.  Instead I would be in favour of a more literal representation of the balance of opinion.

In the instance of the 95% confidence level, for every individual adopting the ‘non-conventional’ stance I would like to see 19 individuals on the other side of the table.  The 19 would be represented by one spokesperson, the only individual who would talk on behalf of that side of the debate.  The other 18 could show their support by raising their hands in support of the speaker or, at the end of a speaker’s statement by saying ‘I agree’.  This, I believe would much better represent the balance of opinion.  It would be necessary to ensure that there is no sense of bullying which I believe the single spokesperson would ensure.  If the person representing the non-conventional approach wished to have another person on their side of the table then they could, as long as 19 people joined the other side of the table.

As a caveat, I recognise that the 95% confidence does is not the view of 100% of scientists, 97% of scientists support the IPCC report.  Therefore, a better representation would be if the stance that humans are responsible for global warming had 95% x 97% (which equals 92.15%) representation.

So far this blog has dealt with an issue of confidence (a measure of scientists’ confidence in their model).  In this case it is not that 95% of scientists 100% hold stance ‘A’ and 5% hold stance ’B’ which actually makes it difficult to represent as all scientists who support the IPCC have some degree of uncertainty, it is not that 5% disagree with the others.  It is simpler when the question is framed such that each scientist takes a position 100%, for example if the debate was centered on the question ‘are the ecological risks posed by GM technologies outweighed by the benefits they offer?’. The same set up could be used with proportional representation of scientific opinion for a debate centering on this question

This blog is just from off of the top of my head but proportional (physical) representation of the opinion of the scientific community makes intuitive sense to me.  If you have any criticisms then please do leave them below.

Thanks